ECON
364 – Topic Eleven
Supply
Side Economics
From:
"Supply
Side Economics" by James D. Gwartney
The Fortune Encyclopedia of Economics, ed. by David R. Henderson
1.
Why and how are marginal tax
rates central to supply-side analysis?
The
role of incentives:
2.
An increase in the marginal tax
rate will reduce the share of additional income that earners are permitted to
keep. What are the two reasons that this adversely affects output? Do
supply-siders support Say's Law?
This is based upon the assumptions regarding the “Backward
Bending Supply Curve of Labor” and the theory surrounding the “Laffer Curve.”
If the
government increases marginal tax rates, that will decrease additional
income that earners keep, thereby affecting output (productivity) for 2 reasons:
1. Marginal tax rate increases, this decreases the payoff
people derive from work (for example, when this occurs many with working spouses
opt out of the labor force), less work, less productivity (incentives
have changed – people choose leisure over work in the labor/leisure
trade-off).
Review: The Backward
Bending Supply Curve of Labor:
(The labor/leisure trade-off) - substitution and income effects -
2.
Marginal tax rate increases,
people turn to tax shelter investments to avoid excess taxes (for example,
investments that generate paper losses from depreciated assets). Therefore
people are spending resources on tax avoidance instead of on productive
activities.
As tax rates rise, investments
that generate paper losses from depreciable assets become more attractive.
So too do business activities
that present opportunities to deduct expenditures on hobbies and personal
amenities.
People are directed into
activities because of tax advantages rather than profitability.
Encouraged to substitute less
desired tax-deductible goods for more desired nondeductible goods.
Waste and
inefficient use of valuable resources are a by-product of this incentive.
3.
What is the difference between a
change in tax rates and a change in tax revenues? What is the "tax base?" Why
does, according to the supply-siders, an increase in tax rates create a less
than proportionate increase in tax revenue? Might there actually be an inverse
relationship between tax rates and tax revenues? Why? Explain the Laffer
Curve.
The inverse relationship is likely when marginal tax rates are
high, but unlikely when rates are low.
The Laffer Curve
(the relationship between tax rates and tax revenue):
4. With a progressive income tax system, why might a tax cut for someone
in the higher tax bracket give them a greater incentive to earn than it does for
someone in the lower tax bracket?
Tax rates cut by 1/3. The guy in the 75% tax bracket goes to 50%
-- keeps $50, rather than $25 of every additional $100 earned - a 100% increase
in the incentive to earn.
The revenues collected from these guys might actually increase.
The guy in the 15% tax bracket goes to 10% -- keeps $90, rather
than $85 of every additional $100 earned -- only a 5.9% increase in the
incentive to earn.
So tax revenue would likely decline here.
The share of the tax revenue
paid by higher income tax payers would go up.
5.
Why did the inflationary
seventies create a receptive environment for the supply-side view? What is tax
bracket creep?
6.
Is there empirical evidence to
support the supply-side view? What did Lindsey's study conclude? Short run vs.
Long Run? What is the difference between a supply-side tax cut and a Keynesian
tax cut? Did the Supply-Side "movement" make an impact?
Lindsey: Used computer simulation model to estimate the
impact of the eighties’ tax-rate changes on the various components of income.
Found with lower taxes, the wages and salaries of high-income
taxpayers were approximately 30 percent larger than projected.
After tax cuts capital gains were approximately 100 percent
higher than projected, and high-income taxpayers’ business incomes was 300
percent higher than expected.
Concluded:
a. people paying themselves more in the form of money income
rather than fringe benefits,
b. increases in business activity,
c. a reduction in tax shelter activity.
Short run effects of tax policy not a strong as long run.
Taxpayers take time to adjust, revenue are even more responsive to rate changes
in the long run.
States study: states with lower marginal tax rates had
much lower deductions and much lower expenditures on tax shelters.
Government revenue begins declining at 50% (Long and Gwartney) or
35% (Lindsey).
Empirical Evidence:
1921-1926 (Coolidge Tax Cuts)
The top marginal tax rates were cut from 73% to 25% (-48%).
Real tax revenue collected from incomes of $50,000 and above
increased from $305.1 million to $481.1 million (+63%). Real tax revenue
collected from those who made less than $50,000 dropped by 45%.
1963-1965 (Kennedy-Johnson Tax
Cuts)
The top marginal tax rates were reduced from 91% to 70%. The
bottom rates were reduced from 20% to 14%.
Tax revenues of the bottom 95% of taxpayers fell from $31 billion
to $29.6 billion (-4.5%). Tax revenues of the top 5% of taxpayers rose from
$17.2 billion to $18.5 billion (+7.6%).]
It is a paradoxical truth that tax rates are
too high today and revenues are too low, and the soundest way to raise
the revenues in the long run is to cut the rates now.
- John F. Kennedy
Speech to Economic Club of New York,
December 14, 1962.
1981-1986 (Reagan Tax Cuts --
supply-side tax cuts)
Top U.S. federal income tax rates declined from 70% to approx.
33%. From 1981 to 1988 (1982-84 dollars), income tax revenue from the top 10%
earners rose from $150.6 billion to $199.8 billion (+32.7%). Top 1% and 5% of
taxpayer’s real revenue was even larger. Tax liability for the bottom 90%
declined from $161.8 billion to $149.1 billion (-7.8%). Note the overall
increase in tax revenue of $36.5 billion (considering only these two groups of
taxpayers -- the top and bottom income earners).
Note: the Bush
tax cuts, taken together and measured as a % of national income are larger than
Reagan's but smaller than Kennedy's.
Kennedy, Reagan,
and Bush Tax Cuts in Historical Perspective
Tax Legislation
|
Tax Cut in Billions of Current
Dollars (a) |
Tax Cut in Billions of Constant
2003 Dollars |
Tax Cut as a Percent of National
Income (b) |
Surplus or Deficit (-) as a
Percentage of National Income (b)
|
The Kennedy
Tax Cuts — Revenue Act of 1964
|
-$11.5
|
-$54.9
|
-1.9%
|
-1.0%
|
The Reagan Tax
Cut — The Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981
|
-$38.3
|
-$68.7
|
-1.4%
|
-2.8%
|
The Bush Tax
Cuts |
|
|
|
The Economic
Growth and Tax Reform Reconciliation Act of 2001
|
-$73.8
|
-$75.8
|
-0.8%
|
1.5%
|
The Job
Creation and Worker Assistance Act of 2002 |
-$51.2
|
-$52.0
|
-0.6%
|
-1.7%
|
|
2003 Tax Cut
|
-$60.8
|
-$60.8
|
-0.6%
|
-3.2%
|
|
|
The Bush Tax
Cuts if Combined in 2003
|
NA
|
-$188.1
|
-2.0%
|
-
|
(a) First year
estimate.
(b) National Income as measured by Net National Product.
|
Source: http://taxfoundation.org/bushtaxplan-size.htm