Before we leave the revenue side of the budget - let's go
over a few more taxes and tax ideas that you might want to consider for your
project:
The Green Tax
Environmental tax reformers argue that the U.S.
could achieve a more efficient tax system by reducing taxes on income and
consumption and raising taxes on pollution.
Tax activities that should
be discouraged, not those that should be encouraged, like work.
Most economists doubt that
the green tax can form the basis for comprehensive tax reform:
1. they are not
sufficiently broad-based to raise enough revenue to replace the income tax.
2.
they are likely to be regressive. Example: the carbon tax (on carbon dioxide –
a tax on the carbon content of fossil fuels) would (according to one study by
MIT econ. James Poterba) impose a tax burden that is more than six times as high
relative to income for taxpayers in the lowest income decile as for those in the
highest income decile.
Are these reasons not to institute the
taxes?
Taxes on Wealth
Income and wealth are different measures of
ability to pay. A person can have high income and little wealth or vice versa,
although the two are usually positively correlated.
The broadest measure of
personal wealth is net worth, which is the value of a family’s assets minus its
liabilities. It is a measure at a point in time.
A personal wealth tax is
advocated by some due to the unequal distribution of wealth. However, they are
hard to administer and are not a major source of revenue for countries that have
them.
A one-time tax on wealth is
a lump-sum tax that does not distort economic decisions – in theory. People
would save more for the future after being taxed.
But would people believe
that it is a one-time tax? Probably not. This would discourage saving. Also,
those who earned the same income but spent it would pay no tax, while those who
saved would bear the burden of the tax. Not exactly a good signal to people
(unless you are a Keynesian economist).
Taxes on Transfers of Wealth
A taxpayer’s death can trigger certain taxes:
the estate tax levied by the federal government and the estate and inheritance
taxes levied by the states.
An estate tax is levied on
the net worth of a decedent, whereas an inheritance tax is levied on the amount
received from an estate by an heir. These two taxes are commonly lumped
together and called death taxes.
The federal estate tax is
levied on the amount of the taxable estate according to a graduated tax rate
schedule. An estate left to a surviving spouse is not subject to the tax.
Money left to charities is also not taxed.
An obvious incentive
provided by a tax on transfers of wealth at death is for taxpayers to arrange to
transfer wealth before dying by making gifts to their heirs.
So the government levied a
gift tax!
These do not raise a large
proportion of revenue for the federal government – partially due to tax
avoidance. Estate planning is big business for tax accountants and lawyers.
Some might argue that
estate taxes are “fair” – in the sense that everyone starts out the race equal
instead of with a large inheritance they did not earn. On the other hand, if
these taxes discourage productivity (because people might work harder in order
to leave something to their kids, etc.), then overall economic growth would
decline.
Taxes on Land and Site Value
Taxes on real
estate property are the main form of wealth taxation in the United States. Most
property tax revenue is collected by local governments. When the value of a
property is determined, the amount of tax is found by multiplying the assessed
value of the property by the levy rate. The levy rate is usually
expressed as dollars of tax per $1000 of assessed value, but it is sometimes
expressed as the mill rate.
Levy rates in different
jurisdictions cannot be easily compared, because some jurisdictions have a high
levy rate but low assessed values, or vice versa. In some jurisdictions, the
assessed value is equal to the market value of the property, whereas
others use fractional assessments that value property at less than market
value.
The problem:
this requires an assessment process. The value of a piece of land
depends, among other things, on its location and amenities. To tax the value of
land holdings, the government would need to determine the market value of each
piece of land in every tax year. Unless sold, the value must be “imputed.” At
the federal level – this would require an army of assessors – to greater
intrusions on privacy than results from the IRS (maybe).
Some
Economic Effects of a Property Tax:
Even if the
supply of land is fixed,
(1)
the levy rate may differ according to the use of the land, so the property tax
affects how land is used. For instance, a higher effective
levy rate may apply if the land is used for residential purposes than if it is
used for agricultural purposes. In this case, the property tax discourages the
use of land for residential purposes.
(2)
Also, vacant unimproved land has a lower value than improved land (cleared,
etc.). If landowners plan to hold land for some length of time, the existence
of the property tax encourages them to hold it in unimproved form.
(3)
Perhaps the most important effect of the property tax is on the quantity of
structures. Although the quantity of structures is fixed at a point in
time, it can vary over time because of new construction and depreciation of
existing structures. Since the value of the structures is taxed by the
property tax, the property tax acts to reduce the quantity of structures.
(4)
Jurisdictions: if some jurisdictions levy higher taxes on property than
neighboring jurisdictions, new homeowners may be encouraged to locate and build
in the lower-tax jurisdictions. This view has been challenged by the argument
that the property tax is a benefit tax (the taxpayer gets a benefit of equal
value). For example – higher property taxes, better schools. What if the
property owner does not have children (like Deb)? (:
(5)
Some believe this tax would reduce urban sprawl and revitalize inner cities.
By taxing land, households would be less inclined to demand large parcels of
property with their homes, reducing flight to the suburbs. Residential density
would be increased. If improvements are not taxed, incentives would be greater
for rehabilitating existing properties within the cities.
More Jurisdiction Ideas
Tax Exporting:
when the burden of a tax is shifted to someone outside the jurisdiction.
Ideally, politicians would
like to levy taxes that burden people who cannot vote in elections. How do
state and local governments do this?
Federal Offsets:
made possible because taxpayers who itemize their federal income taxes can
deduct state and local income and property taxes.
Example:
a New York family in the 28% federal tax bracket pays $5000 in deductible state
and local taxes, it saves $1400 in federal personal income taxes by taking the
deduction, which reduces its taxable income by $5000. In effect, federal
taxpayers pays part of the family’s state and local taxes. Of course, to
offset this, the feds levy a higher tax rate, so the cost of the $1400 tax
saving to the New York family is exported to the taxpayers of the country at
large.
Taxing particular
goods and services likely to be purchased by out-of-state consumers or
visitors to the state.
Example: higher sales taxes on hotel rooms.
Tax Competition:
occurs when a local government sets its tax rate marginally below the tax rates
prevailing in other localities in order to attract the tax base – say, business
and personal income – into its jurisdiction. By “stealing” another locality’s
tax base, a low-tax jurisdiction can collect more revenue despite its lower tax
rates.
But once one jurisdiction
does this, another may retaliate and lower rates even further. In the end, both
states might lose revenue. Although some taxpayers gain from tax competition,
the states must raise revenues in other ways where tax competition is not
possible. These alternative taxes may do even more harm.
In the extreme case, tax
competition may limit local taxing jurisdictions to benefit taxes. These
taxes do not cause people to change locations. Again, a benefit tax is
difficult to levy across the entire population.
And finally -- you should
really consider the following when discussing your tax plan in your project:
Tax “Avoison” by Gordon Tullock
Tax
Avoidance:
taking measures to reduce tax liability that are perfectly legal.
Example: homeowner exemption
Tax
Evasion: taking
measures to reduce tax liability that are not legal.
Example: underreporting income
Both
have implications for resource allocations for society.
Avoison: Both
avoidance and evasion.
Tax
Avoidance
The
Home Mortgage Decision: Would people buy houses anyway? If yes, then there’s
no cost in terms of allocating resources differently. There is the cost of the
tax bureaucracy and tax industry.
If the
tax changes people’s behavior – they buy and sell every time they move, this is
a cost that is caused by the tax.
The
Economic Incidence (costs) of Loopholes
1) Some pay more than others (those who take advantage of the loopholes
and those who do not). The government provides the same set of services but the
cost is distributed in a different way among taxpayers through the tax system.
2)The economy is
distorted by the existence of the tax advantage. Resources
move where they otherwise would not move - assuming that the loophole does
create incentives for people to try to avoid taxes.
3)Some may
choose more leisure over work – because leisure is not taxed but working is.
The allocation of time between work and leisure might cause a social loss. The
cost is the production that is lost.
4)People may not
work as hard. Similar results as above.
Special
Services for the Tax Industry
Another
economic incidence (cost) of tax avoidance is that a very large number of industries exist solely for
the purpose of providing tax exemptions – or their size is much larger than it
otherwise would be.
Tax
accountants and lawyers, resorts
for conferences, real estate, etc.
Corporate
Structure as a Response to the Tax System
The
structure of the corporation can be changed to decrease tax obligations.
As we
discussed - Since
corporate stock is taxed while corporate bond interest is deductible –
corporations are more likely to finance through debt rather than equity (when
they otherwise wouldn’t for efficiency reasons).
Tax Evasion
The terms “black market” or “underground economy” describes the
activities used by people to evade taxes (especially the income tax).
Basically it is underreporting of income (or payment of income in the case of a
payroll tax) in some way or another.
The Cost
of the Underground Economy
Tullock: doesn’t object to the tax avoison but to the activities themselves.
If they were taxed, the profits from such illegal activities would be lower and
hence the profits would go down and fewer people would enter the “industry.”
But why
should fewer people be in any given industry?
Repairman example: Hire a repairman instead of taking off work to do it
yourself. The quality of the work is higher and society doesn’t lose your lost
productivity. Since he is not going to report the income, he will do it for
less money (the real market price).
Should
we object to this tax evasion?
Your
answer may depend upon whether you think the government needs the money.
Economic incidence of Tax
Avoison
It is difficult to know the cost of tax avoision. It
depends upon:
1)will the
government increase tax bases (keeping tax revenue the same)
2)if so, what
will the government use the money for (reducing another tax?)
3)if not, are we
better off with a smaller amount of revenue going to the government
4)an underground
economy is productive – is it more productive because those involved in it do
not pay taxes
5)are those
involved in the underground economy free-riding off others
6)what about the
cost of enforcing the tax code
7)what about the
cost of complying (or not complying) with the tax code
Supply-side
economists focus on incentives-- especially the incentive to work
or not. Their main assumption is that people work more if their wage is
increased (in general). Therefore, cutting taxes (increasing wages) will
lead to more work effort, a larger tax base, and therefore, more tax revenue.
This is based upon the assumptions regarding the theory surrounding the “Laffer Curve.”
Incentives and work -- which is correct:
Substitution Effect:
Income Effect:
GRAPH: (supply curve of labor)
The
Laffer Curve
(the relationship between tax rates and tax revenue):GRAPH
The
Theory:
If
the government increases marginal tax rates, that will decrease
additional income that earners keep, thereby affecting output (productivity) for
2 reasons:
1.
Marginal tax rate increases, this decreases the payoff people derive from
work (for example, when this occurs many with working spouses opt out of the
labor force), less work, less productivity (incentives have changed –
people choose leisure over work in the labor/leisure trade-off).
2.
Marginal tax rate increases, people (including those operating businesses) turn to tax shelter investments to avoid
excess taxes (for example, investments that generate paper losses from
depreciated assets) or move their businesses to places where tax rates are lower . Therefore people are spending resources on tax
avoidance (or tax evasion)instead of on productive activities.
Real productivity is lower than it could be because resources are wasted
producing goods that are valued less than their cost of production -- many goods
are produced that otherwise would not have been produced if it wasn't for people
trying to avoid taxes. Those resources could have produced goods that
actually made peoples lives better off (in absence of the taxes).
Trickle Down:
Policy Conclusions:
Cut income taxes in order to increase tax revenue (through an increase in
productivity and tax collection).
The
main supply-side (tax cut) effects are:
increase
in business activity
reduction
in tax "avoision"
And
therefore: there is an increase in the tax base and therefore, possibly, also an
increase in tax revenue.
The rich pay more: Furthermore, there is an increase in the share of
income tax paid by high income taxpayers when the higher bracket tax rates are
cut (i.e., the rich end up paying more of the total tax bill).
In The Way The World Works, Jude
Wanniski, one of the leading gurus of the "supply-side" school, calls for
discovering the actual shape of the "Laffer Curve."
That part of "The Curve" at which government
revenue is maximized should be pinpointed and fiscal policy implemented to
assure that the economy is moved to that point without further delay.
The "Curve" aside - the supply-side argument can
be seen as a long-run strategy to increase economic growth, not a short-run
policy tool to deal with a recession, for example.
Empirical Evidence
From History - the U.S.:
Four major income tax cuts in the United States -
Keep in mind that tax revenue collected by the U.
S. federal government has typically increased over time. The question is -
does it increase at a higher rate after a major income tax cut. According
to data, it does. Numbers from the U.S. Budget Office.
1922-1928
(Coolidge Tax Cuts)
When the federal income tax was enacted in 1913,
the top rate was just 7 percent. By the end of World War I, rates had been
greatly increased at all income levels, with the top rate increased to 77
percent (for income over $1 million). After five years of high tax rates, rates
were cut sharply under the Revenue Acts of 1921, 1924, and 1926. The combined
top marginal normal and surtax rate fell from 73 percent to 58 percent in 1922,
and then to 50 percent in 1923 (income over $200,000). In 1924, the top tax rate
fell to 46 percent (income over $500,000). The top rate was just 25 percent
(income over $100,000) from 1925 to 1928, and then fell to 24 percent in 1929.
So the
top marginal tax rates were cut from 73% to 25% (-48%).
Revenues received by the federal treasury
increased from $719 million in 1921 to more than $1.1 billion 1929. That's a 61%
increase (there was zero inflation in this period).
Real
tax revenue collected from incomes of $50,000 and above increased from $305.1
million to $481.1 million (+63%). Real tax revenue collected from those who made
less than $50,000 dropped by 45%.
1963-1965
(Kennedy Tax Cuts)
JFK’s tax cuts were passed in the summer of
1964. The
top marginal tax rates were reduced from 91% to 70%. The bottom rates were
reduced from 20% to 14%.
From 1965 to 1968, total federal revenue rose by
30%, from $117 billion to $153.
Tax
revenues of the bottom 95% of taxpayers fell from $31 billion to $29.6 billion
(-4.5%). Tax revenues of the top 5% of taxpayers rose from $17.2 billion to
$18.5 billion (+7.6%).
Top
U.S. federal income tax rates declined from 70% to approx. 33% (and was 28% when
he left office).
Revenues (from all taxes) to the U.S.
Treasury nearly doubled. Revenues increased from roughly $500
billion in 1980 to $1.1 trillion in 1990.
Tax payments and the share of income taxes paid
by the top 1% climbed sharply. For example, in 1981 the top 1% paid 17.6% of all
personal income taxes, but by 1988 their share had jumped to 27.5%, a 10
percentage point increase. The share of the income tax burden borne by the top
10% of taxpayers increased from 48.0% in 1981 to 57.2% in 1988. Meanwhile, the
share of income taxes paid by the bottom 50% of taxpayers dropped from 7.5% in
1981 to 5.7% in 1988.
2003-2008 (Bush Tax Cuts -
supply-side tax cuts)
Economic Growth and Tax Relief
Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRAA) and Jobs and Growth Tax Relief
Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA)
EGTRRA generally reduced the rates of
individual income taxes:
a new 10% bracket was created
for single filers with taxable income up to $6,000, joint filers
up to $12,000, and heads of households up to $10,000.
the 15% bracket's lower
threshold was indexed to the new 10% bracket
the 28% bracket would be lowered
to 25% by 2006.
the 31% bracket would be lowered
to 28% by 2006
the 36% bracket would be lowered
to 33% by 2006
the 39.6% bracket would be
lowered to 35% by 2006
The EGTRRA in many cases lowered the
taxes on married couples filing jointly by increasing the standard
deduction for joint filers to between 174% and 200% of the deduction
for single filers.
Additionally, EGTRRA increased the
per-child tax credit and the amount eligible for credit spent on
dependent child care, phased out limits on itemized deductions and
personal exemptions for higher income taxpayers, and increased the
exemption for the Alternative Minimum Tax, and created a new
depreciation deduction for qualified property owners.
JGTRRA accelerated the gradual rate
reduction and increase in credits passed in EGTRRA. The maximum tax rate
decreases originally scheduled to be phased into effect in 2006 under EGTRRA
were retroactively enacted to apply to the 2003 tax year. In addition, the child
tax credit was increased to what would have been the 2010 level, and "marriage
penalty" relief was accelerated to 2009 levels.
There were also capital gains tax
cuts in both.
The Bush tax cuts had sunset provisions that made
them expire at the end of 2010. But were extended by a two-year extension that
was part of a larger tax and economic package, the Tax Relief, Unemployment
Insurance Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act of 2010.
Income tax revenue rose, going from $925
billion in 2003 to $1.53 trillion in 2007.
Total federal revenue for 2008 dropped
slightly, down to $2.52 trillion, because a recession started that
year. During the same period, income tax revenue dropped slightly
in 2008, down to $1.45 trillion.
After the Bush tax cuts,
the top 1% paid a larger share of all federal
income taxes than before. In 2007 the top 1% of taxpayers earned
22.8% of the nation's income, yet paid 40.4% of all federal income
taxes, whereas in 2004 the top 1% paid 36.89% of all federal income
taxes. So the percentage of income taxes paid by the top 1% went up (this also means that in 2007
the top 1% paid more in federal income taxes than the bottom 95%
paid.)
Criticisms of the Theory
1. Some critics claim that the
elasticity of labor supply is very low:
Wage
elasticity of labor supply:
Therefore, a change in the
tax rate does not actually change people's work or output
very much.
However, these elasticity
estimates are typically short-run estimates. Most
studies do show that the long run estimates are much higher.
For example, Edward Proscott's famous cross-country studies
"found that the elasticity of the long-run labor supply was
substantially greater than in the short-run supply and that
differences in tax rates between France and the Unites
States explained nearly all of the 30 percent shortfall of
labor inputs in France compared with the United States."
(James D. Gwartney, "Supply-Side Economics")
2. Regarding
"discovering the shape of the Laffer curve" to find out what
tax rate will maximize government tax revenue:
The
obvious question that some economists would ask is: how do
we ever find out the actual shape of "The Curve" and where
we are on it?
If, for
sake of the argument, it was accepted that such a "Curve"
exists somewhere out there, it is important to realize that
it would be nothing more than the cumulative subjective
estimations of a multitude of individuals about the relative
advantages of work vs. leisure, consumption vs. savings,
etc.
"The Curve" would be no more
fixed or stable than the expectations and preferences of the
individuals in a particular community. Changes in people's
valuations, revisions in expectations about the political,
social or economic climate and new discoveries of
cost-saving production techniques would all work to make any
hypothecated "Laffer Curve," a shifting, shadowy entity
whose position and shape would be as fluid and erratic as
the imaginative minds of the individuals who comprise the
elements living under "The Curve."
3. Probably an even
more important criticism than the theoretical difficulties
of determining the position and shape of "The Curve" is
the assumption that the goal of fiscal policy should be the
maximizing of governmental revenues.
Why is
that a good policy goal? Maximizing government revenue
means you are also maximizing the opportunity cost of those
resources taken away from the productive sector of the
economy. In a way, this is contradictory to the
theory.
Cut taxes
to increase productivity - the increase in productivity will
generate more tax revenue - then decrease productivity by
moving resources out of the productive sector of the
economy.
4 Although a
secondary idea that comes out of the theory is
that the relatively rich end up paying more of
the tax revenue -- the relatively rich might
still end up better off compared to those who,
most especially, don't pay income taxes.
Because the theory of supply-side economics is
“tax-cuts on income and capital gains,” it
stands to reason that the immediate beneficiary
is going to be those with significant income. In
the United States, the wealthiest 50% of
households pay more than 95% of the income taxes
and the wealthiest 5% pay 50% of the income
taxes. If one group is getting taxed and the
other is not, a tax cut will effectively
increase the disposable income of taxpayers
relative to non-taxpayers. If Jane is in the top
5% of incomes and Bob is in the lowest 5%, a tax
cut raises Jane's income but has no effect on
Bob because Bob was not paying taxes in the
first place. Some would object to this.
However, the
benefits of the tax revenue being spent are
another issue. Do those who pay income
taxes benefit more or less (relative to what
they pay) than those who pay nothing?